Industry-relevant training in Business, Technology, and Design to help professionals and graduates upskill for real-world careers.
Fun, engaging games to boost memory, math fluency, typing speed, and English skills—perfect for learners of all ages.
Enroll to start learning
You’ve not yet enrolled in this course. Please enroll for free to listen to audio lessons, classroom podcasts and take practice test.
Listen to a student-teacher conversation explaining the topic in a relatable way.
Welcome class! Today we will cover the theory behind consumer behaviour. To start, can anyone tell me what factors might influence a consumer's choices?
I think it has something to do with income and what they like!
Exactly! Income and preferences, or tastes, play a significant role. We refer to this decision-making process as the 'problem of choice.'
And how does that affect what they buy?
Great question! Consumers wish to maximize their satisfaction, which we call utility, given their budget constraints. Remember this acronym: I.C.U.- Income, Choice, Utility!
So what if someone has different preferences for the same good?
Good observation! Utility is subjective; different individuals derive varying levels of satisfaction from the same product. Let’s dive deeper into utility now.
So, Cardinal Utility Analysis measures satisfaction numerically. Can anyone explain what Total Utility is?
Isn't it the total satisfaction from consuming a certain quantity of goods?
Exactly! And what about Marginal Utility?
It's the additional satisfaction from consuming one more unit, right?
"Correct! Remember the formula:
Let's move to Ordinal Utility Analysis. Who can tell me what an indifference curve is?
It's a graph that shows different bundles of goods providing the same satisfaction, right?
Good job! An indifference curve slopes downwards because if you want more of one good, you have to give up some of another. Remember: 'More of one means less of the other.'
What does MRS mean?
Marginal Rate of Substitution! It tells us how many mangoes a consumer is willing to give up for one more banana, maintaining the same utility level. MRS diminishes as we consume more of one good.
Now, let’s discuss the budget set. Class, what factors define a budget line?
It’s determined by income and the prices of the goods, correct?
Right! The budget line represents combinations of goods a consumer can afford. If their income goes up, what happens?
The budget line shifts outward!
Exactly! And how about when prices change?
It pivots or shifts based on whether the price increases or decreases?
Perfect! Remember: a change in income leads to a parallel shift, while a change in price pivots the line. Let’s move to discussing optimal choice.
Alright, let’s discuss optimal choice. How does a consumer decide on their best consumption bundle?
They look for the highest indifference curve that touches their budget line?
Exactly! At this point, the MRS equals the price ratio. Can anyone summarize the relationship between preference ranking and budget constraints?
Consumers want to maximize satisfaction within their budget. If their preferences change, their optimal choice may also change.
Well done! Remember, the balance of MRS and the price ratio is crucial in determining the best choice.
Read a summary of the section's main ideas. Choose from Basic, Medium, or Detailed.
In this section, we explore consumer behavior in detail, particularly focusing on how consumers decide on their purchases based on preferences and constraints like income and prices. The section introduces Cardinal Utility Analysis, which quantifies satisfaction, and Ordinal Utility Analysis, which ranks preferences without quantifying them, enhancing our understanding of consumer choices.
Consumer behavior is pivotal to understanding markets, as individual purchasing decisions shape demand dynamics. This section begins with the concept of choice, emphasizing that a consumer aims to maximize satisfaction from available goods within their income constraints. The relationship between income, preferences, and pricing guides these choices.
Key frameworks include:
The section concludes with the implications of preferences on consumer choices, the budget set defined by income and prices, and optimal consumption under budget constraints. The understanding of these theoretical frameworks fosters a well-rounded grasp of how consumers behave in the marketplace.
Dive deep into the subject with an immersive audiobook experience.
Signup and Enroll to the course for listening the Audio Book
In this chapter, we will study the behaviour of an individual consumer. The consumer has to decide how to spend her income on different goods. Economists call this the problem of choice. Most naturally, any consumer will want to get a combination of goods that gives her maximum satisfaction. What will be this ‘best’ combination? This depends on the likes of the consumer and what the consumer can afford to buy.
This introduction sets the stage for understanding consumer behavior in economics. It explains that consumers face a choice regarding how to allocate their limited income among various goods and services to maximize their satisfaction. The 'best' combination of goods will differ for each consumer based on their preferences and budget constraints.
Imagine going to a grocery store with a fixed amount of money. You might want to buy fruits, snacks, and drinks. Depending on what you like and how much each item costs, you'll choose a combination that gives you the most enjoyment without exceeding your budget.
Signup and Enroll to the course for listening the Audio Book
The ‘likes’ of the consumer are also called ‘preferences’. And what the consumer can afford to buy depends on prices of the goods and the income of the consumer.
Preferences are the individual tastes and desires that guide consumer choices. A consumer’s income and the prices of goods determine what is affordable. This interaction between preferences and budget constraints is crucial for understanding how consumers make choices in the marketplace.
Consider two friends, Sarah and John. Sarah loves coffee, while John prefers tea. Even if they both have the same amount of money to spend at a café, Sarah will spend it on coffee, while John will choose tea, reflecting their individual preferences.
Signup and Enroll to the course for listening the Audio Book
A consumer usually decides his demand for a commodity on the basis of utility (or satisfaction) that he derives from it. What is utility? Utility of a commodity is its want-satisfying capacity. The more the need of a commodity or the stronger the desire to have it, the greater is the utility derived from the commodity.
Utility is a measure of the satisfaction gained from consuming goods. It varies from person to person and can change based on circumstances such as location or time. Understanding utility helps explain consumer behavior.
Think of a pizza: one person might find immense satisfaction in a cheese pizza, while another may prefer a veggie pizza. Their differing utility derived from the same good (pizza) illustrates how subjective preferences are.
Signup and Enroll to the course for listening the Audio Book
Marginal utility (MU) is the change in total utility due to consumption of one additional unit of a commodity. For example, suppose 4 bananas give us 28 units of total utility and 5 bananas give us 30 units of total utility. Clearly, consumption of the 5th banana has caused total utility to increase by 2 units.
Marginal utility is a critical concept in understanding how consumers make decisions about consumption. As consumers continue to add more units of a good, the extra satisfaction they receive from each additional unit tends to decrease, which is known as the law of diminishing marginal utility.
Consider ice cream on a hot day: the first scoop might bring a lot of joy, the second scoop still feels great, but by the third or fourth scoop, you may not enjoy it as much, indicating diminishing utility.
Signup and Enroll to the course for listening the Audio Book
Cardinal utility analysis assumes that level of utility can be expressed in numbers. It measures total utility and marginal utility. In contrast, ordinal utility analysis ranks preferences without assigning numerical values.
This distinction is important in economics. Cardinal utility quantifies satisfaction, while ordinal utility focuses on the order of preferences. Consumers might not assign specific numerical values but can express that they prefer one bundle over another.
Imagine a ranking of favorite things: you might say you prefer chocolate ice cream over vanilla, but you wouldn't necessarily assign scores like 8 for chocolate and 6 for vanilla—it's simply a matter of preference.
Signup and Enroll to the course for listening the Audio Book
The quantity of a commodity that a consumer is willing to buy and is able to afford is called demand for that commodity. The demand curve is a graphical representation of the relationship between the quantity demanded and the price of the commodity.
The demand curve illustrates how demand changes with price, typically showing that as the price decreases, the quantity demanded increases, demonstrating the law of demand. This relationship is fundamental for understanding market behavior.
Visualize a market for sneakers: if the price drops from $100 to $70, more people will buy them. The demand curve would slope downward, capturing this relationship visually.
Signup and Enroll to the course for listening the Audio Book
The demand curve shifts due to changes in consumers' income, preferences, or prices of related goods. For instance, an increase in consumer income typically shifts the demand curve for normal goods to the right.
Shifts in the demand curve show how demand can change without a change in the price of the good itself. Understanding what causes these shifts helps in predicting consumer behavior in response to external factors.
If new health studies come out showing that eating vegetables is incredibly beneficial, more people might start buying them even if the price doesn’t change, resulting in a rightward shift in the demand curve for vegetables.
Learn essential terms and foundational ideas that form the basis of the topic.
Key Concepts
Utility: Satisfaction or pleasure from goods.
Total Utility (TU): Overall satisfaction from consumption.
Marginal Utility (MU): Satisfaction from consuming an additional unit.
Indifference Curve: Various bundles giving equal satisfaction.
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS): Rate of substitution between goods.
Budget Set: All possible bundles given income and prices.
Budget Line: Combinations of goods costing total income.
See how the concepts apply in real-world scenarios to understand their practical implications.
A consumer chooses between cookies and cake, maximizing utility based on preferences and budget.
When the price of bananas drops, the consumer can buy more bananas, shifting to a higher indifference curve.
Use mnemonics, acronyms, or visual cues to help remember key information more easily.
When choices are made with care, utility measures how much we dare.
Once there was a shopper who always aimed to maximize her happiness. By carefully balancing her budget, she ensured her choices maximized her satisfaction.
U.T.I.L.I.T.Y: Use Tastes In Living Individual Tastes Yearnings.
Review key concepts with flashcards.
Review the Definitions for terms.
Term: Utility
Definition:
The satisfaction or pleasure derived from consuming a good or service.
Term: Total Utility (TU)
Definition:
The total satisfaction received from the consumption of a given quantity of goods.
Term: Marginal Utility (MU)
Definition:
The additional satisfaction gained from consuming one more unit of a good.
Term: Indifference Curve
Definition:
A graph representing various bundles of goods that provide the same level of satisfaction to the consumer.
Term: Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
Definition:
The rate at which a consumer is willing to substitute one good for another while maintaining the same level of satisfaction.
Term: Budget Set
Definition:
The collection of all consumption bundles that a consumer can afford given their income and the prices of goods.
Term: Budget Line
Definition:
A graphical representation of the combinations of goods that exhaust a consumer's income.